Where do people want to live?

Source: Economist

MANY people would like to up sticks and move somewhere better. But according to new Gallup polling data gathered over the last three years, 16% of adults—or some 700m people—in over 130 countries say they would like to start a new life abroad. The most popular destinations specified are wealthy Western countries, though Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates are also attractive. If everyone got their wish, America’s population would swell by 165m while Canada, Britain and France would each gain 45m new migrants. Those in African countries are keenest to leave, whereas Asian respondents were happiest where they were.

Many would want to live in Malaysia too  (5m-24.9m)!!!

 

Shisha – Is it worse than cigarettes?

Shishasuch as has many names hubbly bubbly or hookah. The trend of smoking shisha has been spreading across the world as many Arabs travel around the globe. In UK, many shops along edgeware road still operate shisha, despite the smoking ban in London(effective in 2007). The response and the type of crowd that visit the ‘shisha joints’ are becoming more varied and young. This hobby/activity is seen as hip  and happening.

Many are under the impression thatsmoking shisha is not really smoking. However, BBC recently came up with an article about shisha and they did state that the health effects are 4 times worst than smoking a normal cigarette. Whilst that is true, the overall effect is very difficult to measure as different people smoke differently (which affects the intake of harmful toxins). So, the next time you feel like having a relaxing time with your mates and decide to take shisha, please think twice!

Tun Mahathir’s talk in London ‘Roles and challenges of youth in 2020’

I decided to attend Tun Dr Mahathir’s (TDM) talk on Tuesday near Holborn. Seeing that I missed his talk on Friday, which was held at Imperial, I did not want to miss the chance to see our leader for 22 years in action. In anticipation that the hall will be crowded, I arrived quite early, only to be made to wait for an hour as Tun was delayed due to the traffic jam(peak time+rain doesn’t help does it?).

He entered the hall, trailed by his wife, Tun Dr Siti Hasmah – they both look so fragile and frail. It is amazing to see him up there at 79 years of age, still able to talk so fluently and crack a lot of jokes(some referring to real incidents/person/country but referred to in an example). He was not assisted by any written material, but gave an amazing talk. His talk was focused on delivering the message about value in society -that we youths need to take action especially against corruption which is happening quite widely and openly in Malaysia. TDM gave pretty good examples and stressed that this must not become a norm. Prices in Malaysia has been rising and this can be a factor in pushing prices even further up – when there a lot of ‘middle person’ involved in any business.

TDM also mentioned about his interview by BBC hardtalk, motioned us to read alternative sources(e.g. Malaysiakini) so that we dont have a biased opinion. He still stands by his stance about western media just highlighting that he was a dictator during his time and not bringing out any democratic things that he did. He quoted,”Have you ever seen a dictator stepping down?” – have we???

About Anwar’s case, he mentioned that helped him a lot during his career in UMNO, but Anwar was impatient to climb up the ranks and become a PM. On this point he advised us to ‘reach the top most level before changing anything’ and if you want to step down, ‘make sure no one can bring you to the court of law after that’ – which seems sensible.

TDM says he is still a supporter of BN and Malaysia stil has hope if its youth can voice their opinion and bring a positive change to the way things are run in Malaysia -highlighting the serioius-ness of corruption.

The Q&A session lasted for so long – many had long statements to make before actually asking something and some asked weird and not relevant questions. Many amongst the audience were keen to know his view on certain people and policies. One such question is with regards to HIshamuddin -is he liable to the drop in ranking of the Malaysian Universities since he became the education minister. To this, TDM said, people should be given a chance to improve the situation, but if they still fail they should step down(not following the Japanese style of committing suicide, but stepping down would be sufficient). Another brave chap asked about the NEP(DEB) -to which he defended the worthy-ness of it and the outcome that created a lot of middle-classed Malays.

Feeling so hungry after the talk, I was so glad that they served food(i think it was nasi with ayam masak korma) – absolutely brilliant!

‘Divorce Is Good for Women’ by Tim Harford(from his book, ‘The Logic of Life’)

This article is written by Tim Harford and is also in his book that I wanted to read(waiting for the paperback version to be released) – it is fully written by him(I did not edit anything, except bold two parts). I thought it was an interesting write-up and it also talks about the origin of division of labour, which we all know how Adam Smith described it. However, he makes us look at history and how the role of man and women evolved. Have a read through it – it would be good to have a discussion on this.

Adam Smith, the father of modern economics, traveled Europe as tutor to the Duke of Buccleugh. But despite his travels, Adam Smith never actually visited a pin factory. While sitting at home in Kirkcaldy and penning the most famous passage in economics, he was inspired by an entry in an encyclopedia. The passage is no less important for that.

Smith argued that a general handyman who turned his hand to the business of making pins,

… could scarce, perhaps, with his utmost industry, make one pin in a day, and certainly could not make twenty. But in the way in which this business is now carried on, not only the whole work is a peculiar trade, but it is divided into a number of branches, of which the greater part are likewise peculiar trades. One man draws out the wire, another straights it, a third cuts it, a fourth points it, a fifth grinds it at the top for receiving the head.

Smith reckoned that ten specialized pin-makers, using equipment designed and built by specialists, could produce 48,000 pins a day. Ten generalized handymen could produce perhaps one pin each. In the “trifling” business of making pins, quite rudimentary division of labor multiplied the output per person almost five thousand times. From a rational choice point of view, dividing labor is a no-brainer.

The division of labor is utterly fundamental to the wealth we enjoy in modern economies. Complicated products, such as the computer on which I am typing this paragraph, are unimaginable without the combined and cumulated efforts of the countless specialists who worked out how to manufacture integrated circuits or how to control a computer using a mouse and a pointer on the screen. Most of those specialists couldn’t boil an egg, let alone survive alone on a desert island. They are dependent on other people’s expertise, if only the expertise of the cooks at the local Chinese take-out, and computer users the world over are dependent on theirs.

Even simple products like the short cappuccino I have beside me would be impossible without the division of labor. Is there anyone in the world who has mastered ceramics, dairy farming and the art of the perfect espresso roast? I’d be bowled over by someone who had any two out of three.

That is all very well, but what does it have to do with marriage? There is not much reason to think that Adam Smith gave the matter much thought: a bachelor, he lived with his mother. Yet marriage used to be one of the fundamental ways to gain from division of labor. Before there were well-developed markets for anything much, and long before you could order a cappuccino, men and women were able to enjoy some of the gains from the division of labor by getting married, specializing, and sharing. Back on the Savannah, one might hunt and the other might gather. In the more recent past, one might be good at guiding a plough and sewing while another would specialize in cooking and household repairs. Nothing about Adam Smith’s story suggests division of labor according to traditional sexual roles, but make no mistake: the family has rational roots. It is the oldest pin factory of all.

By the 1950s, those traditional sexual roles were fundamental in the division of labor within marriage. The ideal husband specialized in breadwinning, getting an education, a good job, working whatever hours were necessary to win promotion, and earning ever more to supply the family with a car, a fridge, a nice house in the suburbs and frequent holidays. His adoring wife specialized in homemaking, cooking, cleaning, entertaining, bringing up the children to be smart and wholesome and taking care of her husband’s emotional and sexual needs.

That was the idea, at least, and in 1965, the average married woman worked fewer than 15 hours a week in paid employment. For the typical woman, a stay-at-home mom, that would be zero hours. The average was pulled up by empty-nesters and the very poor. Meanwhile, the average married man worked over 50 hours a week. The roles were neatly reversed for household work: married women did almost 40 hours a week of non-market work, men fewer than ten. This was division of labor all right, and it was division of labor along sexually lopsided lines.

It was economist Gary Becker who showed the implications of Adam Smith’s pin factory for marriage in the modern age. How had the division of labor become so sexually lopsided? The answer was the interaction of three economic forces: the division of labor, economies of scale, and comparative advantage.

As Becker knew, division of labor works because it unleashes economies of scale. In plain English, one full-time worker earns more than two half-time workers. That is often true for the most basic jobs, but much more so for the most demanding positions. How many top lawyers do half a law degree and then work twenty-hour weeks? How many successful business executives work only Mondays, Tuesdays and Wednesday mornings? And the top earners, at the peak of a long, full-time career, earn much, much more than those half-way through their careers. It is a harsh truth about the world of work that for many professionals, the more work you have done in the past, the more productive each additional working hour becomes: a perfect example of economies of scale.

This means that a household in which both parents work part-time on their careers and part-time looking after children and the home does not make rational economic sense. Two halves are much less than a whole. Economies of scale dictate that, logically, one partner should apply himself or herself full-time to paid work. The other should work at home-making, and only work for money if there is some spare time available after the household chores.

So far this is classic Adam Smith. Where did the traditional gender roles of the 1950s come from? Becker pointed out the implications of the third economic force, the principle of comparative advantage. Comparative advantage says that division of labor is governed not by who is most productive in some absolute sense, but in a relative sense. In Adam Smith’s pin factory, if worker Elizabeth can sharpen two pins a minute and mount four pins a minute in paper, while worker James can sharpen one pin a minute and mount one pin a minute in paper, the logic of comparative advantage says that James should be sharpening pins, even though Elizabeth does the job faster. The relevant comparison is not whether Elizabeth sharpens pins faster than James but whether, relative to him, she sharpens pins faster than she mounts them in paper.

Imagine that James and Elizabeth are married; now, replace mounting pins in paper with looking after babies. Elizabeth is a more productive worker than James but also a more effective parent. James is a bad worker but a worse dad, and so Elizabeth takes the rational decision to stay home baking cookies and looking after the kids, while James tries to scrape together a living as a real estate agent. The logic of comparative advantage highlighted something that most men—except economists—have found it hard to get their heads around: there is no reason to believe that men were breadwinners because they were any good at it. They might simply have been breadwinners because getting them to help around the house would have been even worse.

Gary Becker’s contribution was not to suggest that women make good parents, but to realize that because of economies of scale even a very small difference in innate capabilities could lead to titanic differences in how people actually spent their time. A small difference in relative expertise between men and women would be enough to cause a sharp division of labor across traditional sexual roles. That difference might be because of biological differences, because of socialization, or because of discrimination against women in the workplace, quite likely all three. Rather than arguing for any particular explanation, Becker showed that the difference didn’t have to be big to have big effects.

In the late 1970s, Gary Becker was a widower and a single parent, pouring all his intellectual energy into “A Treatise on the Family,” published in 1981. (A happy footnote: he remarried shortly before the treatise was published.) One of his aims was to understand what was happening to the institution of marriage. Divorce rates had more than doubled in the past two decades, both in the US and many European countries. It was clear that the world of marriage had changed dramatically.

Some commentators have blamed changes in divorce laws for the trend: Ronald Reagan, then Governor of California, signed a bill introducing “no fault” divorce in 1969, meaning that either partner could simply walk away from the marriage by demanding a divorce. Other states followed. But Becker knew that couldn’t be the answer: if the husband wanted a divorce to run off with his mistress, “no fault” divorce didn’t make it easier for him to do that, just cheaper—before “no fault” divorce, he had to get his wife’s agreement, which might mean higher alimony payments. This reasoning suggests that “no fault” divorce rules wouldn’t change divorce rates at all. The only thing that would change was who paid whom to get the divorce. And sure enough, although there was a brief spike in divorce rates as “no fault” divorce allowed a backlog of divorces to be processed more quickly, the legislation appears to have produced no more than a blip in a strong, steady upward trend.

Instead, the divorce revolution was driven by a more fundamental economic force: the breakdown of the traditional division of labor identified by Adam Smith. At the beginning of the 20th century, housework took many hours, and only the poorest and most desperate married women had jobs. As the decades rolled past, technological change made housework less time-consuming. It became easy—and quite common—for older women to enter the workforce after their children were grown and housework was easily manageable.

Once divorce rates first began to climb, it was no surprise that they increased dramatically. There was a rationally self-reinforcing loop at work: the more people divorced, the more divorcees—that is, potential marriage partners—you could meet. That meant that it was easier to get divorced yourself and find a new spouse.

Furthermore, once divorce started to become conceivable, women knew they could no longer think of themselves as one part of an economic unit. Rationality, you will recall, is about thinking ahead and responding to incentives. Realizing that the economic unit might break up, at which point a woman who simply specialized in having children was in serious trouble, it became rational for a woman to maintain career options as divorce insurance. In the division-of-labor world of the 1950s, unhappily married women would rationally stick it out: they had few alternatives. But as more older women were finding jobs, managing their housework more quickly with the aid of washing machines and electric irons, women started to realize that there was an alternative to an unhappy marriage. Divorce was still financially tough but it was no longer economic suicide. And then the contraceptive pill came along, making women—as we have seen—more highly educated, career-minded and employer-friendly.

Did women really need career options before they could get divorced? In all but the most desperately unhappy marriages, they did. Contrary to the popular bar-room grumbles of divorced men, alimony alone doesn’t take women very far financially. Fewer than half of single divorced mothers get any child support at all, and for those who do, child support is just a few thousand dollars a year, typically about one-fifth of the mother’s total income. If a woman, especially a mother, was determined to get a divorce, she almost always needed to find a job. More and more women realized that they had the ability to do exactly that.

That started a second reinforcing loop—some people regard it as a vicious circle. Because divorce was conceivable, women preserved career options. But because women had career options, divorce became conceivable. It became less and less likely that a woman would become trapped in a miserable marriage out of pure economic necessity.

A close look at the statistics backs up this story. Even today, when so many women work for fun or the enjoyment of spending the cash, women tend to work more when they face a higher risk of divorce. There are several ways to guess at that higher risk: you can look with hindsight at who did get divorced and assume that the woman involved might have seen it coming beforehand; you can look at variables such as age, religion and whether parents went through a divorce; or you can ask women how happy they are with their marriages. Whichever way you slice it, women at risk of divorce are more likely to head out for work. The increase in divorce is not because of a change in the psychology of love: it is a rational response to changed incentives.

The changing incentives also altered the way couples behaved within the relationship. In states which introduced “no fault” divorce, while divorce rates did not show a lasting increase, women knew that their husbands could walk away from the marriage without having to buy their agreement with a generous side-deal. That made it riskier to make an expensive commitment to the relationship: riskier to have children, riskier to financially support a husband through school, and riskier to become a homemaker while hubby focused on his career. The economist Betsey Stevenson explored this question using a research approach that should now be familiar, looking at the timing of the new law, state by state. And she found that when states introduced “no fault” divorce and thus gave the husband an easy escape from the marriage, wives were less likely to work while their husbands went through school, but more likely to work full time and less likely to have children. All these effects were quite large; for each decision, between five percent and ten percent of women changed their behavior as the law changed.

A young woman in the early 1970s faced a different world to that her mother lived in two decades earlier. She could see that career opportunities for women had opened up, and there were jobs available if she wanted them. She could see, too, that divorce rates were on the rise and she should not, if she was wise, simply rely on a husband to provide her with an income, because extreme division of labor was too insecure for an age of divorce. Other women her age were marrying later, meaning that there were more men to date and marriage could be postponed. To cap it all, she had access to a safe, reliable way of postponing children until she was ready to have them, meaning she could plan for a long education and several years to establish herself in a serious, high-powered career.

This analysis links divorce, the pill and women’s increasing power and achievement in the workplace in a reinforcing loop. But it would be wrong to “blame” an increase in divorce rates on an increase in women’s professional achievements. There is, after all, no evidence that people are more unhappy with their marriages than in 1950. The opposite is likely to be true, because when they are unhappy with their marriages they can do something about it. One influential study by economists Andrew Oswald and Jonathan Gardner finds that divorcees, unlike widows and widowers, are happier one year after the marriage ends than they were while still married.

Perhaps a more positive way to express the trend is that women’s entry into high-powered careers has given them the option to get divorced if the marriage isn’t working out; and the recognition that that option is important is one of the factors encouraging women’s entry into high-powered careers.

That may sound a little abstract, but economists Betsey Stevenson and Justin Wolfers discovered a chilling example of the way that the increased availability of divorce empowered women. As states passed “no fault” divorce laws, women acquired a credible threat to walk out of the marriage. (The statistics suggest that many of them did not, actually, do this. But the threat is enough.) Stevenson and Wolfers show that the new laws had an unexpected—but rational—effect: by giving women an exit-option, they gave men stronger incentives to behave well inside a marriage. The result? Domestic violence fell by almost a third, and the number of women murdered by their partners fell by ten percent. Female suicide also fell. It is a reminder that the binding commitment of marriage has costs as well as benefits.

Perhaps we should celebrate divorce just a little bit more. First, we should recognize that divorce is no longer increasing. That is rational. The peak in divorce in the 1970s was not, fundamentally, caused by legal changes but by changes in the underlying economics of family life, changes which reduced the incentives to be married.

In the long run, the rational response is not for couples to marry early and marry often; it is to divorce less and marry less, too. Now that the stock of marriages has been decimated by divorce, romantic couples are moving from the boom and bust of marriage and divorce to a more stable arrangement where marriages are delayed until couples are more sure of themselves. And perhaps delayed indefinitely—two of the leading economic researchers in the field, Stevenson and Wolfers, have been a romantic couple for ten years, and remain unmarried.

While the divorce rate has been falling for three decades, it would be a shame if it fell too far. Justin Wolfers comments, “We know there exists something called an optimal divorce rate, and we’re 100 percent sure it isn’t zero.”

The serious entry of married women into the workforce has meant that they spend a little less time baking cookies, and perhaps also that their husbands spend a little more time with the children. It has empowered them to leave marriages that are not working, making them happier and safer from abuse. It has truly been a revolution, and the price of that revolution is more divorce and less marriage. That price is very real—but it is almost certainly a price worth paying.

Fair Trade

When IC(Imperial College) resumed after the winter break, the college only sold fair-trade stuff. I then was curious on whether the farmers really benefit from this. I wrote something in my previous blog. There is also an article on the bbc website which I think would be a good read. Plus there are opinions included if you want to get a varied view.

% of Women in Senior Management Position

I stumbled upon an article on BBC which said that about 38% of firms do not have women in the senior management companies in the UK. Japanese had an even lower figure of 25%. Countries with highest percentages were mostly Asian :

 

1. Philippines – 97%

2. China – 91%

3. Malaysia – 85%

4. Brazil – 83%

5. Hong Kong – 83%

I am quite delighted to see that Malaysian figure is 85%. However, be wary that these surveys can be skewed. Actually, what would be interesting is to have a survey to find out what percentage of companies that do not have men in their senior management…would it be zero???

Stock Markets Plummet

Following the fall in the Chinese market, most other markets followed suit. Why is there a dependency on this emerging market. It is a wake up call that the world in interconnected. As the saying goes, ‘No man is an island’. Hence, we depend on other nations and vice-versa.

So, why do we go to war when peace is more appealing? Anyways, that’s the stir for the day!

World’s Oldest Paper Goes Digital

Founded in 1645, Sweden’s Post-och Inrikes Tidningar newspaper is the oldest in the world. And now it is embracing a paperless society by going digital! And so are most information these days – easily available(except the copyright protection materials).

There a various benefits associated to the limited publication of newspapers. The major impact, is reduction in the use of paper, hence a better environment. Secondly,  is easier to reach the vast majority of subscribers. Also, it is easily accessible from anywhere, without the need of carrying the newspaper around. Personally, I would prefer this compared to normal papers.

Of course, not everything would be 100% flawless. People still prefer the feel of holding a paper and reading it rather than staring at the computer screen or small palmtops.  From the producers point of view, its difficult to reach out to conventional people or places where people have limited Internet connectivity. I would definitely like something to hold and read onmy tube journeys. London Lite and London Paper do keep me entertained if I can get my hands on one, or if it is not too crowded to be opening the huge paper and read it on the tube!

Reading this news brought back memories of the last term. Looking back at our Entrepreneurship idea of E-Flex, I just had a discussion with XQ and he mentioned that Phillips is coming out with something  similar that we planned to do, using GSM instead. Interesting. Being an engineering student, we would definitely want to fit in as innovators, early adopters or worst case, early majority. This is with reference to Everett Roger’s diffusion theory on how a new product is spread across in society. Falling into the lower 50% would be something we would definitely want to avoid.

The Economist : India Overheats

I was reading the Economist and was interested in this article on India. The media constantly talks about China being the next superpower, just lagging behind the US. Why have we neglected India? This second largest emerging market is doing really well – growing 9.2%, just 1.2% behind China. The government predicts that they can sustain a growth of 9% in the coming years.

It is good news – more investors, more job opportunities and more people out of poverty. However, why is India ‘overheating’? Inflation has risen to 6-7%, whereas that of China is just 2.8%. Factories are operating at maximum capacity and the country is currently in deficit. Apparently the domestic output from industries in India cannot afford to meet the rising demand. How to we curb this?

Well, coming back to my previous point as discussed in the interblog debate with Waq, I still stand to my point that control in population expansion is vital to deal with problems that the world is facing. Now, acording to the article in the Economist, “Population growth by itself does not add to prosperity, unless young people are educated and new jobs are created”.

“India’s demographic structure is indeed starting to look more like East Asia when its growth took off.” So, control of the demographic is important to sustain and help the growth of a large country like India.

This week’s Economist has a few good articles. So, do check it out!